4 June 2016

What is ‘patent holdup’? Should it be regulated? If yes, how?

On January 6, 2016, the Liège Competition and Innovation Institute (LCII) organized a half-day conference around the question: “Regulating Patent ‘Holdup’?” (you can find the program and the slides of the presentations here; you can also read the full summary of the proceedings).

The organizers kindly invited me to close the conference by giving some concluding remarks. I reproduce my summary of the conference in this post. (If you prefer to watch the video of my speech, here it is.)

holdup

Throughout the workshop, participants have attempted to answer the following three questions:

  1. What is the problem?
  2. How serious is the problem?
  3. How to solve the problem?

What is the problem?

Bonhomme_neige1

The first question – what is the problem? – concerns the definition of patent holdup. It is widely agreed that a patent holdup may arise in the context of negotiations between a patent holder and an implementer when ex ante licensing is impractical and when the patent holder enjoys a larger bargaining power in ex post negotiations. What separates ‘ex ante’ from ‘ex post’ is the moment when the implementer sinks in some resources that are specific to the patent at stake. The patent holder can then take advantage of the implementer’s reduced flexibility and, opportunistically, extract larger (‘unreasonable’) licensing fees, especially when the patent holder can obtain an injunction for a patent infringement if licensing negotiation fails (as ‘patent trolls‘ and ‘patent privateers‘ are accused of doing) . In the case of standard-essential patents (SEPs), another form of holdup is the ‘patent ambush’, whereby a participant to a standard development process fails to disclose that it holds (or will hold) a patent that is relevant to the standard and only asserts it once the standard is adopted.

How serious is the problem?

Bonhomme_neige2

The second question – how serious is the problem? – is both conceptual and empirical. From a conceptual point of view, several commentators suggest that the problem may be over-emphasized.

  • First, one may conclude too quickly that SEPs confer market power and that market power leads to holdup, while none of these two causal links is clearly established.
  • Second, the possibility exists that it is not the patent holder but the implementer who has the largest bargaining power in licensing negotiations, for instance because of a monopsony position; in this case of ‘reverse holdup’, the patent holder may end up receiving licensing revenues that are lower – and not higher – than the value of their patent.

From an empirical point of view, the question is how to measure the problem.

  • First, several stylized facts suggest that the problem is likely to exist, especially in the field of ICTs where the need for interoperability and the high pace of technological progress imply that most licensing contracts are negotiated ex post.
  • Yet, there is a clear lack of direct evidence, as most licensing agreements are kept secret. One should then rely on secondary evidence by testing if the likely consequences of patent holdup (such as higher final good prices or lower rate of entry in the industry) are observed in reality; however, this methodology is fraught with at least two difficulties: the counterfactual is hard to determine and the lack of secondary evidence is in itself no proof that the problem does not exist.
  • Anyway, as some commentators claim, this debate may be a bit vain as it is not necessary to collect evidence of a market-wide phenomenon to prove the anticompetitive conduct of a particular company.

How to solve the problem?

Bonhomme_neige3

As for the final question – how to solve the problem? – it is first debated whether it should be asked at all: if the problem is largely exaggerated, no solution would indeed be needed. There is an agreement, however, on the need to address properly the issue not only to make standard development processes more predictable but also to preserve incentives to innovate. A first way to solve the problem is to prevent it from happening. This can be achieved through ad hoc contractual arrangements (portfolio licensing, cross-licensing, patent pools) or through regulatory means implemented by standard-setting organizations (such as the definition of (F)RAND licenses).

If this fails, then solutions need to be found to fix the problem when it occurs. Where should these solutions be looked for? Some commentators argue that disputes can be addressed under intellectual property law or contract law. It is also debated whether disputes should be addressed under competition law. Although the issue is not settled, some conditions are stated for competition law to be used to address holdup problems: the theory of harm should be better articulated, and neither the probabilistic context of patents nor the possibility of reverse hold-up should be ignored.

Conclusion

Bonhomme_neige5

In sum, even it was suggested to ‘stop obsessing over hold-up’, the variety of analyses and viewpoints that were proposed during the workshop suggests that the debate over the existence of a systemic or anecdotic problem with patent holdup, and the necessity of remedying it with regulation, is far from over. A heated debate indeed.

 

 

(Photo credit: Stéfan via Visual Hunt / CC BY-SA. As for the snowmen, I downloaded them during the conference to compose my slides, but I forgot to note their origin; my apologies to the right-holders.)

No Comments Leave a comment

Submit comment

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *